Intro
 
Chapter 2

Suggested citation

Download Citation
.
Last updated: October 2012

13.1 Price elasticity of demand for tobacco products

A fundamental building block of economic theory is the fact that increasing (or decreasing) the price of a commodity reduces (or increases) demand for that commodity. Price elasticity of demand refers to the extent to which use of a product falls or rises after increases or decreases in its price. If price elasticity of demand for a product were very low—that is, if it were inelastic—then demand would fall or rise only slightly in response to price changes. For instance, if price elasticity for a particular good were about –0.1, then demand for that good would fall by only 0.1% for every 1% increase in price. Demand would fall by 1% for a 10% increase in price, by 2% for a 20% price increase and so on. Demand for a good with high price elasticity would fall much more sharply in response to price increases. If price elasticity of demand for a good were about –1.0, then demand for that good would fall by 1% for every 1% increase in price. Demand would fall by 10% for a 10% price increase, 20% for a 20% price increase, 100% for a 100% price increase, and so on.

While demand for tobacco products is not as elastic as demand for many other consumer products 1 research has consistently demonstrated that increases in the price of tobacco products are followed by moderate falls in both the percentage of people smoking and the amount or number of tobacco products that remaining smokers consume. 2 , 3 The percentage of people smoking declines because tax increases discourage non-users from starting, encourage current users to quit and, also very importantly, discourage former smokers from starting again. 3 Because increases in tobacco taxes result in higher tobacco prices across the whole population, the effect of even small resulting reductions in tobacco use can be very large across the whole population.

13.1.1 Estimates of elasticity

Why people reduce smoking in response to increases in the price of tobacco products has been a matter of some conjecture—see Section 13.2. However, there is no doubt that they do. The extent to which demand for tobacco products responds to changes in price is an empirical question, the answer to which can be ascertained by measuring trends in consumption as prices and other relevant factors change.

Depending on the size of the price increase, reduced consumption of tobacco products following increases in tobacco taxes can be quite substantial. In 1999, a World Bank review concluded that, all else being equal, price rises of about 10% would on average reduce tobacco consumption by about 4% in developed countries and about 8% in developing countries. 4, 5 In their 2003 meta-analysis reviewing 86 studies published to the year 2001 which examined the price elasticity of demand for tobacco products, Gallet and List 6 found a mean price elasticity of –0.48, meaning that, on average, a 10% increase in price will be followed by a decrease in consumption of 4.8%.

The review conducted by the International Agency for Research on Cancer published in 2011 concluded that studies on the impact of price increases on aggregate demand in high income countries on average find price elasticity of about–0.4, with most estimates from the US and UK falling in a relatively narrow range between–0.2 and –0.6. 7

13.1.2 Various methods of measuring elasticity

Price elasticity can be calculated in many different ways, and various methods have different advantages and different problems (see Section 13.1.6).

Many studies examining the price elasticity of demand have used aggregate data—that is, data at a country or state level on the total amount of tobacco purchased or taxed for the entire population. Some of these studies have analysed changes in taxable or reported sales of all tobacco products, and some have looked at cigarettes alone. Some have measured the weight of product sold, others the number of units. Some studies have compared consumption in the same jurisdiction with different prices over time (time-series analyses). Others have compared consumption in jurisdictions with different prices at the same points in time (cross-sectional studies).

Other studies make use of surveys conducted regularly among school students, adults or households. These might be surveys that ask about smoking habits or they might be surveys about spending on a whole range of household items. i A small number of studies have looked at consumption as reported by a panel of smokers interviewed (about their consumption and various factors which might affect it) before and after tax increases over time. More recently, behavioural economists have examined the response of individuals not to real-life price increases, but rather to price increases simulated in behavioural thought experiments.

Researchers have also used a variety of statistical models for specifying demand and for estimating elasticity. In their comprehensive review, Gallet and List 6 found that resulting estimates of price elasticity from all these sorts of studies were generally fairly similar and did not differ systematically depending on the design or method of analysis used. Studies that measured responses to price changes in the short term tended to report lower elasticity than studies that reported long-run estimates (–0.40 compared with –0.44). Subsequent studies in high-quality journals also tend to report slightly lower estimates, reflecting increasing sophistication in modelling and the greater number of factors also affecting consumption being taken into account. 6

13.1.3 Impact of price increases on uptake, continued consumption and quitting

Data from surveys of individuals across a population allow researchers to examine in more detail the impact of price increases on both smoking participation (that is, whether people smoke at all) and smoking intensity (that is, how much people smoke). Different studies have drawn differing conclusions about the relative contribution of declines in prevalence and declines in smoking intensity. 8  ii

Overall, research among adults 8 indicates that:

  • Roughly half of the impact of price on tobacco consumption results from reductions in prevalence, and roughly half results from remaining smokers smoking less frequently.
  • Higher prices  prevalence by increasing interest in quitting, quit attempts and successful cessation
  • Higher prices can reduce consumption among remaining smokers by reducing consumption by daily smokers.Prices can reduce consumption by increasing the likelihood that smokers will smoke only on some days. 8

Unlike for adults where prices affect both participation and intensity, early researchers assumed that most of the effects of price on young people smoking were on participation, mostly by reducing smoking initiation. Studies examining the relative effects of price on participation and smoking intensity among youth have reached varying conclusions, 9, 10 but those that have used the longest panels of data 11, 12 have generally been able to detect some effect on both initiation and quitting. 13 The review of the literature conducted by the International Agency for Research on Cancer 3 concluded the following:

  • Cigarette prices influence different stages of uptake of cigarette use, with a relatively larger impact at later stages.
    • Most but not all longitudinal studies from high-income countries find that smoking initiation is inversely related to price.
    • As cigarette prices increases, smoking cessation among young people increases.
  • Price has a direct effect on young people, and also an indirect effect through both peer and family influence. 9

13.1.4 Price sensitivity among various population groups

Studies collecting data from individuals also allow researchers to assess how different population groups tend to respond to changes in price. 14

Since young adults more commonly than older adults are occasional rather than regular smokers, it is theoretically possible that they may be less influenced by price changes. However, teenage and younger smokers generally earn lower wages and are less dependent on tobacco, both of which would tend to make them more price sensitive. 15 Early cigarette demand studies by Lewit and colleagues using individual-level data 16, 17 found a strong inverse relationship between price sensitivity and age, with younger smokers reducing consumption much more than adults in response to the same price increases. This finding was thrown into doubt by an influential Rand study by Wasserman and colleagues in 1991. 18 Later studies however 11, 12, 19, 20 supported earlier conclusions of Lewit and colleagues that younger smokers tend to be more price sensitive.

In the US Surgeon General’s review of the literature published in 1994, 21 estimates of elasticity of youth cigarette demand ranged from –0.9 to –1.5 (about three times the level of elasticity of adult cigarette demand). Across all the studies published up until 2001, Gallet and List also found greater responsiveness among younger people, with an average price elasticity of –1.43 for teenagers, –0.76 for young adults, and –0.32 for adults. 6

A comprehensive review of literature on the effect of prices on youth smoking conducted by the International Agency for Research on Cancer 9 concluded that price elasticity of demand for teenagers was somewhere between –0.5 and –1.2%. 9

Studies have differed as to findings about the relative price sensitivity of women compared with that of men. Townsend and colleagues (1994) found that women in the late 1980s and early 1990s in Britain were more sensitive than men to increases in tobacco prices. Chaloupka and Pacula, 22 however, found that the prevalence elasticity iii for young American men was almost twice as large as that for young women. Across all the studies published until 2001, Gallet and List 6 found an average price sensitivity of –0.50 for men, and –0.34 for women. Subsequent studies have generally failed to find gender differences in price sensitivity. 8  iv

Studies in high-income counties have also tended to show greater price sensitivity among lower socio-economic groups. 23 Low-income groups were more responsive to increases in cigarette prices in the UK in the 1980s and early 1990s. 24 , 25 , 26 In the US, smoking rates of young black men are significantly more responsive to changes in price than are smoking rates among young white men. 27

While not every study has reached the same conclusion—different levels of access to cheaper tobacco products over time and in different countries may explain some of the inconsistent findings 28 —the majority of studies in high-income countries have found greater price sensitivity among those on lower incomes. 23 , 28 See Section 13.11 for further details.

Smokers in poorer nations also tend to be more sensitive to price, with estimates of price sensitivity generally around 0.8%, about double that in more affluent countries. 29 Blecher and Walbeek conclude, however, that when changes in affordability rather than changes in price are taken into account, the level of sensitivity in developing countries may be similar to that observed in developed countries. 30

13.1.5 Price elasticity for tobacco products other than cigarettes

US, 31 Canadian 32 and Finnish 33 research has concluded that an increase in the price of manufactured cigarettes can lead to an increase in sales of loose tobacco and other tobacco products. Increases in the price of those products without simultaneous increases in the price of cigarettes are also followed by drops in consumption. 33 In Australia, use of roll-your-own tobacco has increased in the years following substantial increases in tax levels on all tobacco products, and additional increases on RYO tobacco (see Section 2.5 and Section 13.6). Increases in use of roll-your-own have been even more pronounced in countries where taxes on loose tobacco have not kept pace with taxes on cigarettes. 34

13.1.6 Limitations of studies assessing price sensitivity

There is no doubt that smokers are responsive to changes in the price of tobacco products. However there is no single definitive way of quantifying price sensitivity. Studies that use individual-level data and those that use aggregate data are both subject to various limitations.

The reliability of individual-level data is very much dependent on adequate sampling and recall and honesty by respondents about factors such as purchase of illicit tobacco. Under-reporting of numbers of cigarettes (or amount of other tobacco products) smoked is also a significant problem. 35 Using aggregate data on taxable product sales avoids these problems and ensures that researchers are looking at the impact of price changes on the entire market; however, studies that use such data are subject to a number of different limitations.

First, without asking a representative sample of consumers about the prices of the products they are able to buy over time, it is sometimes difficult to determine exactly what the average or typical price increase is (see Section 13.3). Manufacturers use a variety of methods of cushioning consumers from the effect of the increases in taxes. It is by no means straightforward to assess the extent of price increases across a market where retailers engage in various degrees of discounting, ‘specialling’ and bulk-selling and where illicit or tax-free tobacco products may also be available. 

Specifying changing quantities of tobacco products is similarly not straightforward. Studies that measure the weight of product may not sufficiently account for tobacco companies gradually reducing the taxable weight of cigarettes (without corresponding decreases in delivery of toxins). 36 Studies that analyse changes in the number of products generally do not take into account any consumer shift to possibly more toxic tobacco products. 37

Finally, studies often do not adequately take into account all the less-easily-measured factors that affect tobacco consumption, such as negative (unpaid) publicity about tobacco in the media and anti-smoking sentiment in the community. Often changes in such factors coincide with or precede tax increases, and the effects of such factors may multiply rather than simply add to the effect of price increases. v

13.1.7 Concluding note

Despite debates on the finer points of theory and despite all these methodological limitations, there is no doubt that price exerts a profound impact on tobacco consumption. 3 Falls in consumption following large price increases are consistently much more rapid and more significant than falls following implementation of most other tobacco-control policies, and the World Bank has stated that increasing tobacco taxes is the single most effective measure that governments can take to reduce health burdens. 2 Increasing taxes on tobacco is a key plank in every major international tobacco-control strategy. 2 , 38 - 44

Relevant news and research

For recent news items and research on this topic, click  here. (Last updated August 2024)

i An example in Australia would be the Household Expenditure Survey, conducted every three to five years by the Australian Bureau of Statistics, which randomly selects a large number of households to complete questionnaires about all their purchases and amounts spent.

ii See Figure 5.1 in Chapter 5 of the IARC review, p176.

iii The ratio by which prevalence (the proportion of people who smoke at all) rather than consumption (the average amount which people smoke) reduces in response to an increase in price.

iv See IARC Chapter 5, Figure 5.2 page 176

v For a fuller discussion of the methodological difficulties see Chaloupka and Warner 2000 4

References

1. Tennant RB. The American cigarette industry: a study in economic analysis and public policy. New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press, 1950.

2. World Bank. Curbing the epidemic: governments and the economics of tobacco control. Washington: World Bank, 1999. Available from: http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/1999/05/437174/curbing-epidemic-governments-economics-tobacco-control

3. International Agency for Research on Cancer. Effectiveness of tax and price policies for tobacco control. Handbooks of Cancer Prevention, Vol.14. Lyon, France: IARC, 2011. Available from: http://www.iarc.fr/en/publications/list/handbooks/

4. Jha P. Avoidable global cancer deaths and total deaths from smoking. Nature Reviews. Cancer 2009;9(9):655–64. Available from: http://www.nature.com/nrc/journal/v9/n9/full/nrc2703.html

5. Jha P and Chaloupka F, eds. Tobacco Control in Developing Countries. Oxford University Press on behalf of The Human Development Network, the World Bank, and The Economics Advisory Service, World Health Organization, 2000.

6. Gallet C and List J. Cigarette demand: a meta-analysis of elasticities. Health Economics 2003;12(10):821–35. Available from: http://www3.interscience.wiley.com/journal/101520325/abstract?CRETRY=1&SRETRY=0

7. International Agency for Research on Cancer. Chapter 4. Tax, price and aggregate demand for tobacco products. Effectiveness of tax and price policies for tobacco control. Lyon, France: IARC, 2011. Available from: http://www.iarc.fr/en/publications/list/handbooks/

8. International Agency for Research on Cancer. Chapter 5. Tax, price and adult tobacco use. Effectiveness of tax and price policies for tobacco control. Lyon, France: IARC, 2011. Available from: http://www.iarc.fr/en/publications/list/handbooks/

9. International Agency for Research on Cancer. Chapter 6. Tax, price and tobacco use among young people. Effectiveness of tax and price policies for tobacco control. Lyon, France: IARC, 2011. Available from: http://www.iarc.fr/en/publications/list/handbooks/

10. DeCicca P, Kenkel D, Mathios A, Shin YJ and Lim JY. Youth smoking, cigarette prices, and anti-smoking sentiment. Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2006. Available from: http://www.nber.org/papers/w12458

11. Evans WN and Huang LX. Cigarette taxes and teen smoking: new evidence from panels of repeated cross-sections. Department of Economics Working Paper: University of Maryland, 1998.

12. Tauras J and Chaloupka F. Price, clean indoor air laws, and cigarette smoking: evidence from longitudinal data for young adults. NBER Working paper no. 6937. Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1999. Available from: http://tigger.uic.edu/~fjc/

13. Chaloupka FJ and Warner KE. The economics of smoking. In: Newhouse, J and Cuyler, A, eds. The handbook of health economics. New York: Elsevier Science, 2000. 1539-627. Available from: http://econpapers.repec.org/bookchap/eeeheachp/1-29.htm

14. Farrelly M and Bray J. Response to increases in cigarette prices by race/ethnicity, income, and age groups–United States, 1976-1993. Morbidity and Mortality Weekly Report 1998;47(29):605-9. Available from: http://www.cdc.gov/mmwr/preview/mmwrhtml/00054047.htm

15. Ding A. Youth are more sensitive to price changes in cigarettes than adults. The Yale Journal of Biology and Medicine 2003;76(3):115–24. Available from: http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/yjbm/jobm/2003/00000076/00000003/art00004

16. Lewit EM and Coate D. The potential for using excise taxes to reduce smoking. Journal of Health Economics 1982;1(2):121–45. Available from: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science?_ob=ArticleURL&_udi=B6V8K-45BC6NV-B&_user=10&_coverDate=08%2F31%2F1982&_rdoc=2&_fmt=summary&_orig=browse&_srch=doc-info(%23toc%235873%231982%23999989997%23289738%23FLP%23display%23Volume)&_cdi=5873&_sort=d&_docanchor=&view=c&_ct=7&_acct=C000050221&_version=1&_urlVersion=0&_userid=10&md5=f61b82f985ad0bd335c236dc281b4ab6

17. Lewit EM, Coate D and Grossman M. The effects of government regulation on teenage smoking. The Journal of Law & Economics 1981;24(3):545–69. Available from: http://www.jstor.org/pss/725277

18. Wasserman J, Manning W, Newhouse J and Winkler J. The effects of excise taxes and regulations on cigarette smoking. Journal of Health Economics 1991;101(1):43-64. Available from: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science?_ob=ArticleURL&_udi=B6V8K-458XP03-4&_user=10&_coverDate=05%2F31%2F1991&_rdoc=4&_fmt=summary&_orig=browse&_srch=doc-info(%23toc%235873%231991%23999899998%23288487%23FLP%23display%23Volume)&_cdi=5873&_sort=d&_docanchor=&view=c&_ct=8&_acct=C000050221&_version=1&_urlVersion=0&_userid=10&md5=1fe195cce4937f547e0c24ec77f5e3fb

19. Lewit E, Hyland A, Kerrebrock N and Cummings K. Price, public policy, and smoking in young people. Tobacco Control 1997;6(suppl. 2):S17–24. Available from: http://tobaccocontrol.bmj.com/cgi/content/citation/6/suppl_2/S17

20. Chaloupka FJ and Grossman M. Price, Tobacco Control Policies and Youth Smoking. Working Paper no. 5740. Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1996. Available from: http://tigger.uic.edu/~fjc/

21. US Department of Health and Human Services. Preventing tobacco use among young people. A report of the Surgeon General, 1994. Atlanta, Georgia: Public Health Service, Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Office on Smoking and Health, 1994. Available from: http://www.cdc.gov/tobacco/data_statistics/sgr/sgr_1994/index.htm

22. Chaloupka FJ and Pacula RL. Sex and race differences in young people's responsiveness to price and tobacco control policies. Tobacco Control 1999;8(4):373-7. Available from: http://tobaccocontrol.bmj.com/cgi/content/abstract/8/4/373

23. Thomas S, Fayter D, Misso K, Ogilvie D, Petticrew M, Sowden A, et al. Population tobacco control interventions and their effects on social inequalities in smoking: systematic review. Tobacco Control 2008;17(4):230–7. Available from: http://tobaccocontrol.bmj.com/cgi/content/abstract/17/4/230

24. Townsend JL. Cigarette tax, economic welfare and social class patterns of smoking. Applied Economics 1987;19:355-65. Available from: http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/00036848700000007#preview

25. Townsend JL, Roderick P and Cooper J. Cigarette smoking by socioeconomic group, sex, and age: effects of price, income, and health publicity. British Medical Journal 1994;309(6959):923–6. Available from: http://www.bmj.com/cgi/content/full/309/6959/923

26. Townsend J. Price and consumption of tobacco. British Medical Bulletin 1996;52(1):132–42. Available from: http://bmb.oxfordjournals.org/cgi/content/abstract/52/1/132

27. Chaloupka FJ and Wechsler H. Price, tobacco control policies and smoking among young adults. Journal of Health Economics 1997;16(3):359-73. Available from: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=225791

28. International Agency for Research on Cancer. Chapter 7. Tax, price and tobacco use among the poor. Effectiveness of tax and price policies for tobacco control. Lyon, France: IARC, 2011. Available from: http://www.iarc.fr/en/publications/list/handbooks/

29. Lance P, Akin J, Dow W and Loh C. Is cigarette smoking in poorer nations highly sensitive to price? Evidence from Russia and China. Journal of Health Economics 2004;23(1):173–89. Available from: http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pubmed/15154693

30. Blecher EH and van Walbeek CP. An international analysis of cigarette affordability. Tobacco Control 2004;13(4):339-46. Available from: http://tc.bmjjournals.com/cgi/content/abstract/13/4/339

31. Ohsfeldt R, Boyle R and Capilouto E. Effects of tobacco excise taxes on the use of smokeless tobacco products in the USA. Health Economics 1997;6(5):525–32. Available from: http://www3.interscience.wiley.com/cgi-bin/abstract/14681/ABSTRACT

32. Thomson N and McLeod I. The effects of economic variables upon the demand for cigarettes in Canada. Mathematical Scientist 1976;1:121–31.

33. Pekurinen M. The demand for tobacco products in Finland. British Journal of Addiction 1989;84(10):1183–92. Available from: http://www3.interscience.wiley.com/journal/119445417/abstract?CRETRY=1&SRETRY=0

34. Sukin K. Tobacco smokescreen. The Nation.2006. Available from: http://www.nationmultimedia.com/2006/01/22/headlines/index.php?news=headlines_19718718.html

35. Warner K. Possible increase in the underreporting of cigarette consumption. Journal of the American Statistical Association 1978;73(362):314-18.

36. Chapman S. Changes in adult cigarette consumption per head in 128 countries 1986-90. Tobacco Control 1992;1:281-4. Available from: http://tobaccocontrol.bmj.com/cgi/reprint/1/4/281

37. Evans WN and Farrelly MC. The compensating behaviour of smokers: taxes, tar and nicotine. Department of Economics Working Paper. University of Maryland, 1995.

38. Gray N and Daube M. Guidelines for smoking control. UICC technical report series no. 52. Geneva: International Union Against Cancer, 1980.

39. World Health Organization. Tools for advancing tobacco control in the XX1st century: policy recommendations for smoking cessation and treatment of tobacco dependence. Tools for public health. Geneva: WHO, 2003. Available from: http://www.wpro.who.int/NR/rdonlyres/8D25E4D3-BB81-479E-8DF5-7BAF674DB104/0/PolicyRecommendations.pdf

40. World Health Organization. Higher taxes key to battle against tobacco use, says new WHO/World Bank publication. 2000. Available from: http://www.who.int/inf-pr-2000/en/pr2000-53.html

41. Jamrozik K. Policy priorities for tobacco control. British Medical Journal 2004;328(7446):1007-9. Available from: PM:15105328

42. Ministerial Council on Drug Strategy. Australian National Tobacco Strategy 2004-2009. Canberra: Department of Health and Ageing, 2005. Available from: http://www.health.gov.au/internet/main/publishing.nsf/Content/tobacco-strat

43. World Health Organization. MPOWER: A policy package to reverse the tobacco epidemic. Geneva: World Health Organization, 2008. Available from: http://www.who.int/tobacco/mpower/mpower_english.pdf

44. Australian Government. Taking preventative action: Government's response to Australia: the healthiest country by 2020. Canberra: Department of Health and Ageing, 2010. Available from: http://yourhealth.gov.au/internet/yourhealth/publishing.nsf/Content/report-preventativehealthcare

Intro
Chapter 2